Health Care Service Delivery Reform

Background

The National Quality Strategy (NQS), established as part of the Affordable Care Act, serves as a catalyst for a nationwide focus on quality improvement efforts and approaches to measuring quality. The NQS has three goals: better care, healthier people and communities, and lower-cost care. In order to achieve these goals, all care should be person-centered. Individuals (and caregivers, if appropriate) need to be full partners in all discussions and decisions related to care. This individualized care encompasses compassion, empathy, and responsiveness to the individual’s expressed preferences. For many Americans, health care is uncoordinated, and quality is uneven. In addition, care can be difficult to obtain, and the cost is increasingly unaffordable. 

Cost is an issue for employers as well. In the search for lower premiums, employers often make repeated coverage changes. As a result, individuals and families with employer-based insurance often experience discontinuity in their health care. Such changes also make it difficult for patients to establish trusting clinician-patient relationships that foster effective communication. 

The Affordable Care Act (ACA) included several provisions to address affordability and quality concerns. They include improving primary care delivery and developing financial incentives to improve care quality, coordination, and cost-effectiveness. 

The ACA also established the Center for Medicare & Medicaid Innovation, known as the CMS Innovation Center. The center is testing payment and service-delivery models designed to control spending while enhancing the quality of care. Beneficiaries will benefit from innovative approaches and other reforms that improve care quality and affordability. 

Primary care: Primary care is usually the entry point to the health care system. 

Practitioners triage and address new conditions and needs, encourage and initiate preventive health activities, and coordinate with other parts of the system. Research suggests that health care systems with solid primary care foundations have better quality, lower costs, better population health, and fewer health disparities. 

Growing shortages in the primary care workforce and the wide gap between payment for primary care and that for specialist services are concerns. Approximately 83 million Americans live in officially designated primary care health professional shortage areas. Experts observe that the income disparity between primary care physicians and specialists discourages medical school graduates from choosing primary care careers. 

Team-based care: Patients also benefit from well-coordinated care managed by a team of professionals with the necessary skills to serve patients’ needs. The numerous demands, range of needed skills, and expectations of primary care suggest that primary care is best provided by a team whose members consult and coordinate with one another, as well as with the patient (and any caregivers, if appropriate). Professional team members practice to the full extent of their licenses and provide services with a clear definition and understanding of roles and responsibilities. 

People with multiple chronic conditions, in particular, can benefit from treatment by health professionals from a variety of disciplines. The team’s composition may vary according to patient needs. Customarily it includes physicians, Advanced Practice Registered Nurses, social workers, pharmacists, nutritionists, family caregivers, and home and community-based service providers. 

Value-based purchasing/payment and value-based benefit design: A growing practice among large purchasers and employer coalitions is to link payment to the performance of health plans, health care systems, providers, and clinicians to improve their clinical and service performance. Such “pay-for-performance” systems can take many forms, including paying a fixed fee to a provider to provide certain specified services to the patient or to care for a patient with certain health conditions during a specified period of time. All these initiatives are intended to reward enhanced quality of care, greater efficiency, or lower costs. Improving quality, public reporting of performance, and lowering costs all have similar goals. However, these different approaches can lead to quite different provider behavior and patient experience. They can also have varied negative unintended consequences. Incentive programs assess clinical care and outcomes, member access to services, and patient-reported experience. They should be grounded in evidence-based measures. Some insurance designs include consumer incentives—for example, reduced cost-sharing for specific services—intended to encourage appropriate use of services (see also this chapter’s section on Value-Based Purchasing). 

Employers can provide information about quality and efficiencies to consumers and can encourage them to use this information when they choose health plans and providers by giving them comparative cost and quality information. 

Value-based purchasing (VBP) advances the idea that buyers should hold providers of health care accountable for the cost and quality of care, that is, the “value” of care they provide. VBP provides incentives for providers and consumers, such as lower payments to providers who do not meet targets and reduced or increased charges as an incentive to encourage consumers to use health care in ways that help maintain their health (e.g., by seeing providers for recommended follow-up visits and preventive services) or control costs (e.g., by avoiding unnecessary emergency department visits). Although improvements in quality can reduce costs, they may also increase costs or be cost-neutral. While cost is a critical concern for consumers, cost alone is not a measure of quality. Therefore, it cannot serve as the sole determinant of value. 

Commercial health plans and public payers use financial incentives in benefit design by lowering or removing cost-sharing for high-value services or well-performing providers. For example, the ACA eliminated cost-sharing for specified, evidence-based preventive services. Incentives are most effective when those directed at consumers and those directed at providers are mutually reinforcing. 

Provider incentives: Clinicians and other providers will drive the transformation of the delivery system, but consumers, purchasers, and payers must also participate. Provider incentives often take the form of increased or reduced payment. For example, providers who achieve high quality and efficiency may receive bonus payments or higher volume. Providers who perform poorly may be subject to penalties, such as the denial of payment increases. Nonfinancial incentives directed at providers also can affect quality. One example is found in Medicare Advantage. Health plans that achieve 5 stars, the highest quality score, are open for enrollment at any time during the year, not just during the once-a-year enrollment period. 

Consumer incentives: Individual consumers can play a role in promoting better care and making the best use of health care resources. Generally, incentives are intended to make consumers more cost-conscious and price-sensitive in their health care choices. Some purchasers or payers offer incentives to encourage beneficiaries to use particular services (e.g., evidence-based preventive or screening services), go to physicians and hospitals that achieve higher-quality results, and use resources more efficiently. Under the latter incentive, a payer creates high-performing mini-networks in which cost-sharing is lower than it is for providers in other networks. 

Reference pricing: Reference pricing is a mechanism used by a health plan, employer, or payer to set a maximum payment (i.e., the “reference price”) for a specific service. Usually, the limit is set to ensure a sufficient number of providers for beneficiaries to choose from. This allows consumers to choose other providers, but at a higher cost if they select one that charges more than the reference price. Large, self-insured employers often have information from claims data about how service costs vary. They also can measure the quality outcomes of specific services. If made available to consumers, this information on quality and cost can help them make informed decisions about where to seek care.

All-Payer Claims Databases (APCDs) play an important role in promoting health transparency, quality care, and payment reform. APCDs include medical, pharmacy, dental, eligibility, and provider files from private and public payers. They can provide critical information about health care utilization and costs. However, the U.S. Supreme Court’s Gobeille v. Liberty decision limited states’ ability to require reporting from self-funded employer-sponsored health plans directly. 

HEALTH CARE SERVICE-DELIVERY REFORM: Policy

HEALTH CARE SERVICE-DELIVERY REFORM: Policy

Value-based purchasing (VBP)

In designing value-based benefits and engaging in VBP, public and private payers should be required to employ incentives that ensure the most effective use of health care resources. This helps keep health care affordable. 

Cost alone is an inadequate indicator of value. 

Supply actionable and accurate information that is readily understandable to most consumers. 

Incentives should not create access barriers or discourage consumers from seeking care. 

Consumer incentives should not be based on attaining bio-metric goals such as weight loss, hypertension control, etc. 

(See also policies in this chapter’s section on Value-Based Purchasing). 

Reference pricing

Reference pricing for services should be employed when: 

  • price variation for the same service is known and documented, 
  • patient outcomes for the specific service are measured, 
  • consumers receive information that compares the quality and cost of the providers offering the service, and 
  • there are sufficient providers available who accept the reference price. 

Establishing all-payer claims databases

State policymakers should establish and develop all-payer claims databases. In developing these databases and public reporting and transparency efforts, states should consult with affected parties, including consumer representatives. States should also be encouraged to standardize data for greater comparability and analysis. 

States’ ability to collect comprehensive data from all sources is critical to the accuracy and effectiveness of all-payer claims databases. Since the Supreme Court’s Gobeille decision has resulted in a significant exclusion of data and potentially skewing analysis, efforts to continue to collect comprehensive information, including self-insured plan data, should be supported. These efforts include state voluntary data collection efforts, state provider reporting requirements, or establishing a federal reporting requirement. 

(See also policies in this chapter’s section on Value-Based Purchasing). 

Found in Health Care Service Delivery Reform